![]() |
RDG
online Restitution Discussion Group Archives |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
||||||||||||
|
I have a question
about subrogation and I would be grateful for anyone's thoughts.
The question is about the ability of a guarantor of a
secured debt to have the benefit of the creditor's securities, once the
guarantor pays the creditor. This ability is secure in all civilian systems
(eg Civil Code of Quebec art. 1656(3); BGB s. 774). It was made part of
the law of England by the Mercantile Law Amendment Act 1856, s. 5, after
common law decisions suggested it was not. Most common law jurisdictions
have cognate legislation.
To me, this seems to make perfect sense. The reason for
my question is that the weight of commentary suggests the contrary. Burrows
questions it (at 83), and Charles Mitchell in The Law of Subrogation
says that it is "unjustifiable" (at 59). Goff & Jones doubt whether the
rule should apply to securities of which the surety was unaware, or those
taken after the guarantee was executed (at 604).
The reason for questioning the surety's ability to take
over security rights is (i) there is no genuine intention built into the
agreement between surety and creditor, that the surety will have the benefit
of any securities (Burrows); and (ii) the surety cannot claim to have
an undestroyed proprietary base, nor can he claim that he never took the
risk of the debtor's insolvency (Mitchell). Therefore it is said there
is no justification for the surety's acquiring the securities.
It seems to me that these arguments miss the point. The
point is that the surety is guaranteeing a particular risk. He is guaranteeing
to the creditor that the debt will be paid. He is not guaranteeing any
other risk or any larger risk. If the creditor has real security for the
debt, then the creditor's risk is reduced. So then should be the surety's.
The only way to ensure that the surety's risk is no greater than the risk
taken by the creditor is to provide that the surety shall have the benefit
of any security, once he has paid the creditor.
This reasoning extends even to securities taken after
the guarantee is signed. The reason is that the surety's risk must be
exactly the risk of non-payment by the debtor to the creditor, in an ambulatory
sense. After all, if the risk of default by the debtor goes up (eg because
of a business failure), then so goes up the risk which the surety is insuring.
Thus if the risk of default goes down (where the debtor gives a new security),
so should go down the risk which the surety is insuring. It also extends
to securities of which the surety is unaware. It is inherent in the guarantee
that it covers the exact risk to which the creditor is exposed, whatever
that may be.
I suppose another way to look at is analogous to marshalling.
The creditor could, if he wished, realize on the security (extinguishing
it) and then go after the surety for any deficiency. If he chooses to
go after the surety first, why should this enure to the benefit of others
(unsecured creditors of the debtor)?
Finally, this reasoning is supported by the rule that
the guarantee is unenforceable (at least to the extent that the surety
is harmed) if the surety does not protect the security (cf CCQ art. 2365;
BGB s. 776). Recent authority holds that this rule is so fierce that it
can operate even in the face of an express term in the guarantee which
purported to exclude it (First City Capital Ltd. v. Hall (1993),
99 DLR (4th) 435 (Ont CA)). Similarly, if the creditor materially changes
the contract with the debtor (eg giving more time to pay), the surety
is discharged (at least to the extent that the surety is harmed). These
rules only makes sense on the basis that the surety is guaranteeing a
particular risk, and so is excused if the risk is enlarged by the creditor.
Any thoughts??
Lionel Smith <== Previous message Back to index Next message ==> |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
» » » » » |
|
![]() |
|||||||||
![]() |