![]() |
RDG
online Restitution Discussion Group Archives |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
||||||||||||
|
The following
(longish) chunk from the current draft (so E&OE) of my thesis may help on
the preferences aspect of Lionel Smith's recent query: in short, there is
a dispute as to who gets the preference recovery in this context, the trust
or the general creditors but on principle it should be the general creditors.
Sorry that I haven't had time to distill the American cases directly on
point: but I am trying to submit next month and am up to my neck in proofreading!!
(By the way, liquidators etc may sue to recover preferences
though recovery only benefits the secured creditor - Kratzmann
and Octavo say so more or less in Australia; I am not sure of
the UK authority; in the US they can't.)
Simon Evans. Distributional patterns and policies.
While the previous Subsection has determined that the
proceeds of an action for breach of fiduciary duty or another claim to
proprietary relief by an insolvent company may be subject to a charge,
this is not the case in relation to the proceeds of some at least of the
statutory avoidance powers. The distributional patterns for property recovered
by a liquidator differ according to the particular grounds of recovery.
Whereas the proceeds of a misfeasance action(1) are held subject to the
chargee's interest (since the misfeasance action does not confer any new
right but merely creates a summary procedure by which the liquidator may
vindicate existing pre-insolvency rights of the company),(2) some controversy
attends the distribution of recovered preferences and transactions at
an undervalue and the proceeds of wrongful or insolvent trading actions.(3)
The question, therefore, arises, when conduct may be characterised either
as giving rise to a proprietary remedy or as triggering various statutory
avoidance or recovery powers which distribution policy should prevail.
Preferences.
The Yagerphone principle.
It was established in In re Yagerphone Ltd(4)
that the proceeds of a preference action are held for distribution to
the unsecured creditors and not subject to any securities. But, in Australia
at least, it appears that, according to dicta of the High Court in N
A Kratzmann Pty Ltd (in liq) v Tucker [No 2],(5) non-money preferences
consisting of specific and identifiable property are, when recovered,
subject to security interests attaching prior to the preferential disposition
because the recovery is based on avoidance of the preferential disposition,
and the security interest is treated as continuing throughout.(6) On the
other hand, monies recovered in respect of a preferential payment are
not the same monies as those paid away preferentially and title to them
is not dependent on any prior rights in respect of the monies paid away
so no security interest attaches.(7)
[Discussion of the Yagerphone principle in
Australian law omitted]
The better view is that In re Yagerphone Ltd
remains good law in Australia, an anomalous exception to the principle
that insolvency law does not override proprietary entitlements determined
by the general law.(16) [Omitted]
In summary, therefore, it appears that recovered preferences,
except for specific and identifiable property charged prior to its preferential
disposition and the proceeds of such property, are to be distributed among
the unsecured creditors of the insolvent.
Applying the Yagerphone principle.
It follows from the previous discussion if the liquidator
proceeds under the preference provisions against the recipient of a preferential
payment in respect of which a proprietary remedy is also available, the
proceeds of recovery will be available for the general creditors alone.(19)
However, if the secured creditor has a charge on the company's right of
action for breach of fiduciary duty, it may require the liquidator to
sanction enforcement of that right of action by the company.(20) In such
cases the liquidator ought to allow the secured creditor to proceed. The
discretionary power contained in s 588FF of the Corporations Law is sufficient
to ensure that the recipient will not be subjected to a double liability.
However, s 241(4) of the Insolvency Act provides that the powers conferred
under ss 238-241 operate without prejudice to the availability of any
other remedy. Nonetheless, the power conferred in s 239(3) is one to restore
the position to what it would have been if the company had not given the
preference. Given that limitation, it is unlikely that an order will be
made under s 241 if the recipient has already been forced to disgorge
its receipt by the secured creditor.
It should not be thought surprising that the proceeds
of recovery are applied in a different manner depending upon whether recovery
occurs under the preference provisions or otherwise. In re Yagerphone
Ltd is a policy motivated redistribution to unsecured creditors rather
than a principled protection of their interests against preferential repayments.
Recall that the "wrongfulness" of preferential payments is the distortion
of the process of rateable distribution. On the other hand, recovery of
preferential payments on the basis of lack of authority to make them or
a breach of fiduciary duty is more directed to preserving the quantum
of assets in the estate. In both cases, if absent the preference the secured
creditor would have had the benefit of security in the property, that
ought to remain the case. There is no basis for extending the In re
Yagerphone Ltd principle to recoveries under proprietary actions.
Consider now the following case:
Example 2: T, a trustee, commits a breach of trust by
paying trust funds into its general account. It then uses those funds
to discharge its own debt to D. The balance of the general account is
dissipated. T becomes insolvent and its liquidator recovers the amount
paid to D as a preference. B, the beneficiary of the trust, claims that
the recovered preference represents the proceeds of the breach of trust
and is held on constructive trust for it.(21)
This case differs from Example 1 above in that the debt
discharged is owed by, and not to, the fiduciary.
Two issues arise. First, whether B has a proprietary
claim to the recovered preference at all. Secondly, whether that claim
prevails over the principle derived from In re Yagerphone Ltd.
The decision of the Court of Appeal In re EVTR(22)
supports B's argument that he or she should have a proprietary claim.
The claimant lent money to a company for the specific purpose of enabling
it to purchase a particular piece of equipment. The company went into
liquidation before the equipment was supplied. The supplier repaid the
purchase price to the company less some charges. The claimant asserted
that the company's receivers held the repaid money on trust for him. On
uncontroversial principles, typified by Barclays Bank Ltd v Quistclose
Investments Ltd,(23) the borrower held the money received from the
lender on trust to be applied for the specific purpose for which it had
been lent. Again uncontroversially, one would expect that upon failure
of the purpose for which the money was lent the borrower would hold the
money on trust for the lender. Accepting the Court of Appeal's conclusion
that the purpose had failed, is any difference made by the fact that at
the time of the appointment of the receiver (or its decision not to proceed
with the purchase) the borrower no longer held the money on the initial
trust but had paid it to the supplier and financier? The Court of Appeal
held that it did not. Dillon LJ applied what he described as "a long established
principle of equity", namely, that if a trustee receives property "because
of, or in respect of," trust property, he or she will hold in as a constructive
trustee.(24)
"It is a long established principle of equity that, if
a person who is a trustee receives money or property because of, or in
respect of, trust property, he will hold what he receives as a constructive
trustee on the trusts of the original property."
So when the supplier and financier repaid the balance
of the money to the borrower, it was received "because of, or in respect
of," the trust money and was held on constructive trust for the lender.(25)
Bingham LJ said that the repayment was a "direct result" of the original
holding of the fund as trustee and the balance "may reasonably be regarded
s not having been paid out at all".(26)
"[T]the company certainly held the fund on trust in the
first instance. The purpose for which the fund was paid out partially
failed. The repayment to the [receivers] was a direct result of the company's
original holding of the fund as trustee. The balance which was recovered
may reasonably be regarded as not having been paid out at all."
It seems, therefore, that this case supports the possibility
of reconstitution of the trust, seemingly in a remedial manner,(27) despite
the fact that the trustee has become a mere debtor to the beneficiary.
(It does not appear to have been argued that the constitution of the secondary
trust was preferential. Presumably it would have been valid as a condition
attached by the lender to the property when first disposed of to the borrower.)
The reconstitution need not be as a result of repayment of the traceable
proceeds of the former trust money; it is enough if money or property
is received because of or in respect of the trust property.
An similar approach was adopted in the United States
of America by the Court of Appeals for the Tenth Circuit on the first
hearing of In re First Capital Mortgage Loan Corporation.(28)
A trustee deposited trust funds in its general account and then used them
preferentially to discharge its existing debts. The court accepted the
argument for the beneficiary that the recovery of the preference by the
trustee in bankruptcy amounted to a return of the trust property to the
debtor-trustee's successor, revived the trust and created an equitable
obligation on the bankruptcy trustee to return the funds to the beneficiary.
(It is important to recall, however, that unlike In re EVTR the
debtor-trustee's payment was a breach of trust.) The result would be similar
if the trustee's creditor knew that the trustee's indebtedness was being
discharged with trust money. Then, the money received is subject to a
charge in favour of the beneficiary and if the money repaid to the liquidator
comes from the charged fund the liquidator would on general principles
hold the recovered funds subject to a charge in favour of the beneficiary.
This was essentially the situation that faced the United States Court
of Appeals for Fourth Circuit in Angeles Real Estate Co v Kerxton.(29)
Simplifying somewhat, the insolvent assigned one-half of the proceeds
of a promissory note to one of its creditors but, despite the assignment,
when the note was collected, paid all the proceeds of the note to a third
party in discharge of an antecedent debt. It does not appear that the
third party knew of or had notice of the assignment. The payment was recovered
as preferential and the assignee claimed that the trustee in bankruptcy
held a one-half interest in the recovered proceeds for it. The court agreed,
emphasising that "recovery of the preference was a recovery of those same
funds" in which the assignee had at least an equitable lien as a result
of the assignment(30) and, therefore, that there was a charge over the
recovered preference in favour of the beneficiary. However, on the subsequent
rehearing en banc of In re First Capital Mortgage Loan Corporation,(31)
the Court of Appeals for Tenth Circuit reversed its earlier decision and
distinguished Angeles Real Estate Co v Kerxton. It was held that
the recovered preference was held for the unsecured creditors and the
beneficiary had to prove as such because the Bankruptcy Code stipulated
that the property was recovered "for the benefit of the estate".(32) The
court pointed out that outside bankruptcy neither the trustee nor the
beneficiary had any remedy against the company to which the payments had
been made as it was a purchaser in good faith without notice. Moreover,
to confer priority on the beneficiary, now an unsecured creditor, would
frustrate the Congressional purpose of facilitating the prime bankruptcy
policy of equality of distribution.(33)
" As a practical matter ... we do not think it equitable
that one general unsecured creditor of the bankruptcy estate should be
made whole by virtue of the exercise of the trustee's avoidance powers
while others must make do with their share of the bankruptcy estate ...
Indeed, if such a result attended the exercise of the trustee's preference
powers, Congress' purpose in granting the power [that is, facilitating
the prime bankruptcy policy of equality of distribution among creditors
of the debtor] would be frustrated".
Returning, then, to the facts of Example 2, is the preference
recovered, in the language of Re EVTR, "because of ... or in
respect of" or as "a direct result of" the original trust property?(34)
The better view must be that the preference is recovered by exercise of
specific statutory powers that leave no room for the operation of the
principle identified In re EVTR. (This may be a somewhat problematic
distinction in the context of provisions that render the preferential
payment void or treat it as never having occurred.)
This must be so, because outside insolvency, B had no
proprietary remedy against T once T paid the traceable proceeds of the
trust funds(35) to D (and no proprietary remedy against D unless D had
knowledge of the source of the money he or she received).(36) B thereupon
became a unsecured creditor of T and ought to be treated as such in the
insolvency. Outside insolvency, B's proprietary claim against T would
be revived only if T repaid money into the account (or segregated a fund)
with the intention thereby of reconstituting the trust.(37) So, in the
absence of such a repayment, no proprietary remedy is available and the
relationship between trustee and beneficiary in respect of the misappropriated
money, as recognised in In re First Capital Mortgage Loan Corporation,
is merely that of debtor and creditor. Were the position to be different
in insolvency, B would have an inappropriate incentive to commence insolvency
proceedings.(38)
But suppose, then, that T had made such a payment into
the account with the appropriate intention to reconstitute the trust.
If this payment were effective to reconstitute the trust, it would have
the effect that B would recover more on the insolvency than it would have
done had the payment not been made. Therefore it would be a preference
if the other statutory conditions were satisfied.(39) It follows that,
as no action by T would be effective to reconstitute the trust,(40) B
would be an unsecured creditor of T and there is no reason why recovery
of the preference should change this.(41)
Consider, now, a third case:
Example 3: T, a trustee of a trading trust, uses trust
funds to discharge debts owed to D that were incurred in the management
of the trust business. T becomes insolvent and its liquidator recovers
the amount paid to D as preferential. G represents the general creditors
of T and D represents the trust creditors.
This example is directly comparable with Example 2 except
that the debt discharged with trust assets is a trust debt. The issue
is among whom the recovered preference ought to be distributed, the trust
creditors alone or all the creditors of the trustee. Normally, the non-trust
creditors have no right of recourse to trust assets for the payment of
their debts.(42) It follows that if the recovered preference is distributed
among them they will receive a benefit they could not otherwise have received.
In principle, therefore, the preference should be distributable among
the trust creditors alone. this will have the additional effect of reducing
the claims of the trust creditors on the non-trust assets. The principal
problem in this context will always be the liquidator's unwillingness
to fund the action, because it cannot have recourse to the recoveries
and the costs of recovery are not costs of the liquidation having priority.(43)
Now, if as in Example 3, that the trustee makes the
payment from trust assets to discharge a debt owed to a trust creditor
preferentially,(44) it is unclear whether the recovered preference should
be available for all the creditors of the insolvent or bankrupt or merely
for the trust creditors.(45) It follows from the previous paragraph that
if the recovered preference is available for distribution among the general
creditors of the trustee, they receive a benefit they could not otherwise
have received, that is, recourse to (the proceeds of) trust assets for
the payment of their debts. In principle, therefore, the recovered preference
should be distributable among the trust creditors alone. McPherson JA
of the Queensland Court of Appeal, writing extrajudicially, has justified
this conclusion by reference to Re Suco Gold Pty Ltd (in liq)(46)
and noted that to the extent that trust liabilities are reduced by recovery
of the preference and distribution, non-trust assets are freed from the
claims of trust creditors should the trust assets be insufficient to meet
the claims of the trust creditors.(47) However, against this it must be
observed that if the recovered preference is available only for the benefit
of trust creditors then it has no impact on the net assets of the trust
and liabilities to trust creditors. (McPherson JA does, however, observe
that trust creditors may prove for a dividend from non-trust assets so
long as the dividend paid to the general creditors equals or exceeds that
paid to the trust creditors out of the trust assets. (ibid.%%%McPherson
(1985), p 158.) To that extent alone non-trust assets are freed from the
claims of trust creditors.) Moreover, there is scant statutory warrant
for limiting the distribution of the recovered preference to the trust
creditors.(48) It is also difficult to reconcile such a limitation with
the construction of preference provisions In re Yagerphone Ltd
requires. Accordingly, it appears to have been held In re McLernon;
ex parte SWF Hoists and Industrial Equipment Pty Ltd v Prebble (49)
that the recovered preference is available for distribution to the general
creditors. This is to be regretted for the reasons of principle given
above and here trust principles should prevail over insolvency principles.
Preferences and the Yagerphone principle: conclusion.
Except in the anomalous situation considered in Case
3, the In re Yagerphone Ltd principle prevails over other principles
that might make recovered preferences available for proprietary claimants.
But the secured creditor will generally be entitled to the benefit of
the company's proprietary claim as part of the subject matter of its charge
and may proceed against the recipient of the company's property. However,
in such proceedings, it will not have the benefit of the presumptions
of insolvency available to the liquidator and will have to prove an actual
breach of duty if its claim is based on such a breach.
(1) Insolvency Act, s 212; Corporations Law, s 598.
(2) Coventry and Dixon's Case (1880) 14 ChD
660; Re Asiatic Electric Co Pty Ltd [1970] 2 NSWR 612. See Oditah
(1992a). This was regarded as "an unwholesome state of things" in In
re Anglo-Austrian Printing and Publishing Union [1895] 2 Ch 891,
p 895.
(3) [Omitted]
(4) [1935] 1 Ch 392. Similarly, it appears that the United
States, courts have rejected the argument that property recovered as a
preference is the proceeds of a right to avoid a disposition, a right
to which the security attached before the commencement of the insolvency:
see Sanborn (1990), pp 1387-1388. One obvious reason is that the right
to avoid preferences is not the company's right but the liquidator's.
Another is that the right is not merely contingent on insolvency but does
not come into existence until the insolvency commences: compare Prentice
(1990), p 272. Because of 11 USC ¤522(a) (see above, n 174) it could be
only by regarding the recovered preference as the proceeds of such a right
that the recovered preference could be subjected to prior securities.
For discussion of the theoretical doubts surrounding In re Yagerphone
Ltd, see Wheeler (1993).
(5) N A Kratzmann Pty Ltd (in liq) v Tucker [No 2]
(1968) 123 CLR 295, pp 301-304. See also Re Margart Pty Ltd (in liq);
Hamilton v Westpac Banking Corporation (1984) 9 ACLR 269; Bayley
v National Australia Bank Ltd (1995) 16 ACSR 38; Starkey v APA
Transport Pty Ltd (1993) 12 ACSR 15.
(6) Note that if the recipient was a purchaser in good
faith for value and without notice of the charge the security interest
will not be enforceable against him or her. But if he or she knew or ought
to have known that the company might become insolvent, the transaction
will be avoidable as a preference. And arguably the security ought to
be enforceable against the property in the company's hands: see Lowther
v Carlton (1741) 2 Atk 242 [26 ER 549] and Wilkes v Spooner
[1911] 2 KB 473 for the limitations of the good faith purchaser defence.
(7) N A Kratzmann Pty Ltd (in liq) v Tucker [No 2]
(1968) 123 CLR 295, pp 301-304. [Omitted]
(16) [Omitted]
(17) See also Keay (1994), p 570; O'Donovan (1993), p
67. Compare Goode (1990), p 54.
(18) Starkey v DFC of T (1993) 11 ACLC 558,
p 567 per McPherson JA; cited in Bayley v National Australia Bank
Ltd (1995) 16 ACSR 38, pp 42-44. Both decisions concerned the legislation
prevailing before the enactment of Pt 5.7B of the Corporations Law.
(19) No case appears to hold that traceable money preferences
recovered as such are subject to the principle of N A Kratzmann Pty
Ltd (in liq) v Tucker [No 2] (1968) 123 CLR 295.
(20) If the payment caused crystallisation of the charge,
the money paid does not form part of the company's estate. It is then
a question of priorities between the company and the chargee. On the traditional
approach, because the company's entitlement depends on its having the
payment set aside, its right will be characterised as an equity and the
company's equitable interest will prevail. But see Linter Group Ltd
v Goldberg (1992) 7 ACSR 580, above, text at n 51. Arguably the secured
creditor will not need the liquidator's or court's leave to proceed, as
the stay on actions in relation to the property of the company does not
apply to actions by a secured creditor to realise its security: Corporations
Law, ss 471B and 500(2).
(21) Compare, generally, Sherwin (1989), p 327, n 121.
(22) Re EVTR; Gilbert v Barber [1987] BCLC 646.
Similarly, if a solicitor acting for a company in administration and holding
a lien for unpaid costs on the proceeds of an action taken on behalf of
the company transfers that sum from the client account to the office account,
and, recognising that this is a contravention on the action to enforce
a security without the consent of the administrator, retransfers the sum
to the client account, the solicitor acquires a lien on the new balance
of the client account: Euro Commercial Leasing Ltd v Cartwright and
Lewis [1995] 2 BCLC 618. The case is, perhaps, explicable on the
basis that the administrator's leave would have been given as of course.
(23) [1970] AC 567.
(24) [1987] BCLC 646, p 651b-c
(25) Presumably, however, it was held on a constructive
trust on the terms of the secondary trust (not the initial trust) which
would arise on the failure of the purpose: see Barclays Bank Ltd v
Quistclose Investments Ltd [1970] AC 567.
(26) [1987] BCLC 646, p 652g.
(27) However, it is difficult to see that there had been
a breach of trust.
(28) In re First Capital Mortgage Loan Corporation
872 F 2d 335 (10th Cir 1989).
(29) Angeles Real Estate Co v Kerxton; In re Construction
General Inc 737 F 2d 416 (4th Cir 1984).
(30) id 737 F 2d 416 (4th Cir 1984), pp 419, 420. Compare
N A Kratzmann Pty Ltd (in liq) v Tucker [No 2] (1968) 123 CLR
295 on recovery of the same property as that paid away preferentially.
(31) In re First Capital Mortgage Loan Corporation
917 F 2d 424 (10th Cir 1990), p 429.
(32) id 917 F 2d 424 (10th Cir 1990), p 427, quoting
from 11 USC §550(a). See also 11 USC §541(a)(3).
(33) 917 F 2d 424 (10th Cir 1990), p 428.
(34) It should make no difference that in a personal
bankruptcy the preference is repaid to the trustee in bankruptcy.
(35) This remains true even if the swollen assets theory
of tracing explored in Chapter 4 is accepted, then. For if T retains property
that that theory identifies as traceable proceeds of B's funds, then a
proprietary claim should be possible in respect of them. But if T retains
no such proceeds, that is, no assets of his or her own out of which he
or she might have discharged the indebtedness to D, then there should
be no proprietary claim. See below, Chapter 4, Section V.
(36) It is clear that a secured creditor of the trustee
has no proprietary remedy in respect of the repaid preference if the security
became fixed after the preferential payment was made: In re Yagerphone
Ltd [1935] 1 Ch 392. However, it is impossible to argue that by parity
of reasoning the beneficiary ought to have no proprietary remedy because
In re Yagerphone Ltd depends not on analysis but on policy considerations.
(37) James Roscoe Ltd v Winder [1915] 1 Ch 62.
(38) Prentice argues, in relation to Insolvency Act,
s 238, that such incentives may be discounted because the fact of insolvency
is a precondition of the avoidance power vested in the liquidator: Prentice
(1987), p 77. However, this misses the point of the argument of Jackson
(1986), Chapter 6, and others. The problem with such incentives to bring
on insolvency proceedings is not that they exist -- an argument which
might legitimately be met by Prentice's argument -- but that they are
differential incentives for different creditors or classes of creditors,
thus undermining the insolvency legislation's attempt to solve the common
pool problem. In relation to s 238 there is no differential incentive
so Prentice's conclusion, if not the reasoning, is correct.
(39) These are likely to be satisfied as a matter of
course. The intention to prefer (if one is required) is almost certainly
to be found in the reconstitutive intention.
(40) In the unusual circumstances where T could recover
the money from D, it is arguable that the money should be held on constructive
trust for B.
(41) It has been suggested that the preference provisions
do not apply to such a case because the trustee and beneficiary are not
in a relationship of debtor and creditor, a precondition for the operation
of the preference sections. The competing authorities are discussed in
Ashburner (1933), p 149. The Insolvency Act appears to resolve the matter
in favour of the view that such repayment may constitute a preference:
ss 382(1) and 382(4) in the case of personal insolvency and Insolvency
Rule 13.12, paras (1) and (4). In Australia, following dicta of Lord Halsbury
in Sharp v Jackson [1899] AC 419, p 426, the matter has been
settled in favour of the view that such a repayment may constitute a preference:
see, for example, Re Donovan; Ex parte ANZ Banking Group Ltd
(1972) 20 FLR 50, pp 68-69 (Fed Ct of Bankruptcy) [etc]
(42) See, generally, McPherson (1985); Re Suco Gold
Pty Ltd (in liq) (1983) 33 SASR 99; Octavo Investments Pty Ltd
v Knight (1979) 144 CLR 360. Nor do the trust creditors have any
such direct right. (The trust creditors as between themselves are entitled
to the trust assets in the order applied in administration actions, not
the order specified by the bankruptcy or insolvency legislation (because
these do not apply to assets held on trust, but see Re Suco Gold Pty
Ltd (in liq) (1983) 33 SASR 99) or in order of the creation of the
debts (McPherson (1985), pp 154-155).) If the trustee discharges such
a debt with his or her own funds, then he or she has a right of recourse
to the trust assets for that amount and a lien on the trust assets to
secure that right. A trust creditor may succeed to that lien by subrogation
(McPherson (1985), p 150, n 87) and that lien constitutes property available
for distribution amongst the trustee's general creditors in bankruptcy
or insolvency. If, however, the trustee has not discharged the debt, he
or she may have recourse to the trust assets but only in order to pay
trust debts. That right may be exercised by the trustee in bankruptcy
or liquidator. However, the funds recouped are not divisible among the
trustee's general creditors but only among the trust creditors.
(43) See Anderson (1992), pp 183-192.
(44) [Omitted]
(45) As a procedural matter, in an insolvency the recovered
preference should be paid to the corporate trustee, but it was left unclear
in Octavo Investments Pty Ltd v Knight (1979) 144 CLR 360, pp
371-372, to whom the recovered preference should be paid in the case of
a bankruptcy. However, In re McLernon; ex parte SWF Hoists and Industrial
Equipment Pty Ltd v Prebble (1995) 130 ALR 609, it was held that
the preferences should be paid to the trustee in bankruptcy and not to
the trustee of the trust.
(46) (1987) 33 SASR 99 (see McPherson (1985), p 157).
(47) McPherson (1985), p 158.
(48) Though s 588FF(1)(g) of the Corporations Law allows
for an order "providing for the extent to which, and the terms on which,
a debt that ... was released or discharged to any extent by ... the [preference]
may be proved in the winding up of the company", this does not allow an
order providing for the terms on which the other debts of the company
may be proved.
(49) (1995) 130 ALR 609.
------- <== Previous message Back to index Next message ==> |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
» » » » » |
|
![]() |
|||||||||
![]() |