![]() |
RDG
online Restitution Discussion Group Archives |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
||||||||||||
|
Hello all
In his message in this thread, Steve Hedley, with the
subsequent approval of Gordon Goldberg, took issue with my discussion
of Cotter v Minister for Agriculture,
a case in which a contractor had agreed to excavate the bed of a river
for a group of farmers (pursuant to a Department of Agriculture scheme
under which the Department paid half the costs). The contractor discovered
rock at much greater quantities than foreseen, and sued for the value
of the extra work done. He succeeded, according to Murphy J, "in contract,
or quasi-contract". I argued that there could have been no liability in
contract because it was impossible to follow the contract procedures to
claim the extra payment. However, Steve objected that
What is the difficulty ? The building contractors are
not charities. Of course they are doing any additional work on the basis
that that they will be paid for it. This satisfies the "reasonable bystander"
test easily enough, surely. Or as Allan Axelrod has put it, isn't there mutual intent that the work be performed
and if not covered by contract paid for at reasonable value? In principle, I can see how this might apply in many
situations (though in practice the courts seem most reluctant to imply
terms even on the basis of the reasonable bystander test). However, a
point I should have made abundantly clear in my summary of the case, but
did not, was that, because there was only a finite amount of money which
the Department would make available to them for the work, the farmers
at all stages intended that the work - however much there was to be done
- would be done for a fixed price. It was on this basis that they approached
the contractor, and on this basis that the negotiations were conducted
and concluded. Indeed, it was on this basis that the farmers at all times
proceeded. In these circumstances, since the fixed price was the only
basis upon which the farmers intended to contract, there would be no basis
for a reasonable bystander to assume that the contractor expected payment
above the fixed price.
Complicating the matter somewhat, however, is the undoubted
fact that the written contract, although it embodied the fixed price,
also contained a clause with a mechanism for charging for extra work:
an engineer could certify their necessity and price. No engineer was ever
appointed, the mechanism was never operable or operated. Now, the reason
why the contract contained the clause was because the contractor's solicitor
dug out a standard form contract and had the parties sign it, and the
standard form contract contained that clause. One of the virtues of such
standard form contracts is that, when they are appropriate, they contain
the wisdom of the industry on the proper balance to be struck between
the parties (many charterparties and bills of lading are excellent examples
of this; so too are standard form building contracts). One of the vices
of such standard form contracts is that, when they are inappropriate but
applied, they cause havoc between parties. That is what happened here.
The contract was entirely inappropriate for the work being done. It was
inappropriate not least because it contained a mechanism which was contrary
to the intention and agreement of the parties. But their intention and
agreement might be seen to come through, nonetheless, by virtue of the
fact that they never took the steps necessary to activate that mechanism:
they never appointed the engineer to make the determination as to the
necessity and value of the extra work. In the end, therefore, I return
to my point that, on the facts of the contract as between the farmers
and the contractor, there was no basis for liability in contract for the
extra work.
Steve went on to comment that
I am not sure what more Eoin wants, when he
asks for the "indicia of a contract". Offer and acceptance, consideration, and intention to create legal relations.
Btu whatever it is, he would surely find it
in the pre-contractual negotiations of the parties, a major function of
which is to settle which items of work are to be paid for under the contract
and which are extras. Gordon Goldberg, writing in Steve's support commented to like effect: the failure was by mutual consent; accordingly,
there was a variation of the agreement; but the price of the extra work
was not fixed by the terms of the variation; and so an undertaking to
pay on a quantum meruit was necessarily implied - cf. s. 8(2). In Cotter, neither the pre-contractual negotiations nor the parties execution
of the contract would reach this result, because the negotiations settled
that all the work would be paid for out of the fixed price. There could
therefore have been no pre-contractual agreement as to extra payment for
extra work, nor could there have mutual consent that the agreement be varied,
since at all times the farmers intended and expected to pay no more than
the agreed fixed price for any and all work done. Of course, Steve's analysis would be applicable in cases
where negotiations were conducted under the shadow of a standard form
contract which both parties intended to enter, since all of the standard
form building contracts contain extras clauses. However, in those cases
where the issue of extras is not dealt with at all in the precontractual
negotiations and not included in a specially drawn up contract (either
because it is too small for a standard form, as was the case in Cotter,
or because it is a case in which each issue is sought to be decided in
advance but this issue is simply not considered), then a contract analysis
based on what the parties actually agreed will not supply answer. In these
circumstances, a non-contractual might very well be appropriate, and that
non-contractual quantum meruit could be directed to reversing an unjust
enrichment. In which case, the analysis would follow along the lines sketched
by Ewan McKendrick in his essay in Cornish et al eds Essays for Jones
and discussed by me in my last email on the point.
Finally, as to Gordon Goldberg's support of Steve's message, even though
the Sale of Goods Act would not apply to building contract cases, the
analogy is important if only because Chalmers was, to a very large extent,
codifying a century's worth of common law, and many of the cases so codified
contained principles which were not confined to the sale of goods context.
The underlying common law principles could therefore be applicable to
building contracts cases. However, even assuming that
the farmers could not take advantage of their
own wrongful failure to appoint an engineer by claiming that it constituted
a frustration of the agreement to pay for the extra work; and so they
were regarded as having repudiated the agreement and thus liable on a
quantum meruit or in damages - cf. s. 9(1) and (2). or that
the failure was a genuine frustration, which
the parties chose to ignore; and so the farmers were liable on a quantum
meruit - cf. s.9(1) However, the issue between Steve and myself is not whether the farmers
ought to have been liable on a quantum meruit (we both agree that the
farmers ought to have been made liable to pay a reasonable price), but
whether that quantum meruit is contractual (as Steve has it) or restitutionary
(as I argue).
Best from Dublin
Eoin
EOIN O'DELL <== Previous message Back to index Next message ==> |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
» » » » » |
|
![]() |
|||||||||
![]() |