![]() |
RDG
online Restitution Discussion Group Archives |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
||||||||||||
|
Banner
Homes certainly seems to be based on the "detrimental reliance" form
of constructive trust (this ties in with the analogy to proprietary estoppel
Edwin Simpson mentions, as it is this type of constructive trust which may
overlap with PE). My sense is that in any event, constructive trusts which
perfect an intention (such as Re Rose) deal with exceptional instances -
Re Rose itself is fairly confined, another eg is a constructive trust arising
from a donatio mortis causa of land - the exceptional circumstance of an
impending death. If I can also join the shameless plug camp, I consider
these (and the detrimental reliance trust) in my book on Informal Acquisition
of Rights in Land (2000) Sweet & Maxwell.
In terms of a detrimental reliance constructive trust,
I still have some difficulty extending these where there is no "net loss"
by the claimant (even accepting the broad nature the detriment may take
following Gillett
v Holt). Banner Homes had not really lost anything, but they had instead
failed to make a gain: their position was the same as it would be if they
had not relied on D's words / actions. All that they could claim to have
lost is a purely speculative chance to look for other means of bidding
for the land.
The analogy between the Banner Homes principle and proprietary
estoppel begs the same question as regards detriment.
Many thanks to all who responded to my initial query
- I'll be kept busy reading for some time!
Nick Hopkins
On Mon, 15 Jan 2001 14:25:12 -0500 Lionel Smith wrote:
Many congratulations to Edwin on the new edition
of Lewin. I await the next boat from London carrying books ... meanwhile,
with the arrival of the last one, we can also say congratulations
to Peter Birks on the magnificent achievement of English Private Law
(OUP 2000). I would also join Edwin in the shameless plug camp
to say that Banner Homes is treated briefly in Kit Barker and Lionel
Smith, "Unjust Enrichment", ch 21 in David Hayton ed Law's Future(s)
(Hart 2000), 428, 431, in which a large number of people try, under
22 headings, to make predictions about where the law is going. My own reaction upon reading Banner Homes was mild
astonishment that it was decided without noticing the direction in
Australian law towards protecting reliance. To be fair, proprietary
estoppel is mentioned as having something to do with something. We
should fear "Pallant v Morgan equity" because whenever we name something
by a case we are admitting intellectual defeat. I think in Banner
Homes there is no discussion of breach of fiduciary duty and so the
holding cannot be so explained.
Is there authority (in English law, in
particular) for a constructive trust based on advantage to the trustee,
rather than detriment by the beneficiary? I would have thought no trust could be based on
that alone, as generally we allow people to derive advantages. But
if we ask whether there are constructive trusts without detriment
in the subtractive sense, ie the plaintiff's loss of the property
now the subject of the trust (which is the sense in which there was
no detriment in Banner Homes), then I think there are a lot. Even
if we put aside constructive trusts based on wrongdoing, like Meinhard
v. Salmon, AG Hong Kong v. Reid, and Soulos v. Korkontzilas, there
are still a lot, namely every constructive trust which perfects an
intention or which is activated by detrimental reliance. Into the
former (perfecting intention) goes Re Rose. Into one or the other
of perfection or detrimental reliance might go mutual wills, every
secret trust if they are not express, and every trust which arises
when I promise to transfer or declare a trust of specified property
and value has been given for the promise (excepting a promise to transfer
ownership of goods). See generally R Chambers, "Constructive Trusts
in Canada" (1999) 37 Alta L Rev 173. Peter Birks might fit Banner Homes into subtractive
unjust enrichment by saying that it is a case of interceptive subtraction.
The general difficulty with this angle is that if the plaintiff was
entitled to the asset in question, interceptive subtraction seems
unnecessary (as Peter points out in "At the Expense of the Claimant:
Direct and Indirect Enrichment in English Law" (2000) Oxford U Comparative
L Forum 1 at ouclf.iuscomp.org, at note 45, Re Rose can be understood
just in this way, as making an equitable entitlement out of an opportunity
based on transferor's intention, so making interceptive subtraction
unnecessary). On the other hand, if the plaintiff was not entitled,
unjust enrichment/interceptive subtraction cannot make him so without
making a logical circle. The entitlement must be justified independently.
Detrimental reliance seems to be a good candidate
in Banner Homes; the discussion of "advantage" to the defendant seems
to be nothing more than another way of talking about detrimental reliance,
ie the plaintiff's position now, as measured against what it would
be if the plaintiff had not relied on the defendant's words or actions:
"It is necessary that, in reliance on the arrangement
or understanding, the non-acquiring party should do (or omit to do)
something which confers an advantage on the acquiring party in relation
to the acquisition of the property; or is detrimental to the ability
of the non-acquiring party to acquire the property on equal terms.
It is the existence of the advantage to the one, or detriment to the
other, gained or suffered as a consequence of the arrangement or understanding,
which leads to the conclusion that it would be inequitable or unconscionable
to allow the acquiring party to retain the property for himself, in
a manner inconsistent with the arrangement or understanding which
enabled him to acquire it." "There was evidence, to which I have referred, that
the existence of the arrangement led Banner to regard the site as
'out of play'; that is to say, the existence of the arrangement made
it unnecessary, and inappropriate, for Banner to consider the site
as a potential acquisition for its own commercial portfolio. But,
as the judge himself recognised, one of the reasons why Luff wanted
Banner kept 'on board' -- and so did not disclose its own doubts as
to the future of the joint venture -- was that, 'if dropped, Banner
might emerge as a rival for the site'. In other words, Luff saw it
as an advantage that Banner's belief that the site was out of play
should be maintained. Luff wanted to keep Banner out of the market."
Lionel |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
» » » » » |
|
![]() |
|||||||||
![]() |