Date:
Fri, 11 Feb 2005 17:39:49
From:
Adam Kramer
Subject:
Remoteness
On
the latest discussion:
Price:
I agree with David that the price is relevant to remoteness. For
me it is because the price is a relevant factor in determining what
responsibility the other party can be assumed to have taken. I think
that the 'foreseeability without tacit assumption' theory collapses
in the face of the old taxi example:
Bill
Gates gets into a taxi at 11.30am and asks the driver how much it
costs to get to the airport. £15, says the driver. Bill tells the
driver that he has a meeting at the airport at 12pm with some very
easily-offended people, and that if he is late then a £100 million
deal will definitely collapse and Bill will personally lose £20
million in profits. He asks if the driver can promise to get him
to the airport in time for the meeting. "No problem guvnor", says
the driver. But he fails.
Of
course, the driver is not liable even though he foresaw (through
specially communicated information) that £20 million would be lost
as a result of breach of the undertaking to arrive by 12pm. However
if the driver had replied to Bill's question with: "No problem guvnor,
but the journey will cost you £100,000", then we can be sure that
the driver has assumed responsibility. The price increase has "signalised"
(Lightman QC, Seven Seas Properties Ltd. v Al-Essa (No. 2) [1993]
1 WLR 1083 , 1088 (Ch D)) the assumption of responsibility. The
increase in price is not necessary for such an assumption - if the
taxi driver was known to be a billionaire or a compulsive gambler,
or the airport was next door, then Bill might also reasonably interpret
the driver as taking responsibility - but it does the job.
Concurrent
liability and Doughty v Turner: I agree with Jason and
Andrew that contract limits tort. Anyway, where the tort duty is
due to an assumption of responsibility, the scope of that assumption
will be governed by exactly the same factors (at the same time-
the time of contracting/assuming responsibility) as the scope of
the contract duty - indeed, contract judges can learn a few tricks
from tort judges as to working out the scope of assumed responsibility
(see particularly Banque Bruxelles v Eagle Star / South Australia
Asset Management v York Montague). I think John Cartwright
talks about this in his classic article [1996] CLJ 488. Also, it
is my view that the scope of responsibility for personal injury
will not be as nicely sculpted by price/insurance and other known
factors, since most people cannot be reasonably assumed to take
responsibility for their own personal injury arising from breach
however cheap the service. Parsons v Uttley Ingham might
be based on similar reasoning. I have a sneaking suspicion that
there is still a problem in Robert's Doughty example though,
but will have to give it some wet-towel-around-the-head thinking.
Strict
Liability: Robert, I don't see a problem with contract liability
being strict and yet the scope of responsibility being often dependant
upon foreseeability. Both are subject to the parties' agreement,
it is merely that it is generally normal to take a promise as being
subject to strict liability but a scope of responsibility for consequences
that is limited by factors dependant upon why the promisor is making
the promise (to make money) etc.
Adam
Kramer
<<<<
Previous Message ~ Index ~ Next
Message >>>>>
|