Date:
Fri, 11 Feb 2005 18:05:25
From:
Robert Stevens
Subject:
Remoteness
As
an inclusionary rule HvB is clearly insufficient. No one
thinks that all loss which is suffered which is reasonably foreseeable
is recoverable either in contract or tort (SAAMCO, Chester
v Afshar etc).
Whether
we should abandon HvB as an exclusionary rule is another
issue.
In
those cases where the tortious duty depends upon a voluntary assumption
of responsibility (eg Brown v KMR) the contract test must
apply. These cases are decided in this way because the duty in tort
arises from a 'voluntary assumption of responsibility' (i.e. the
duty to take care arises from the promise to take care both in contract
and tort.)
If
you take the view (per Lord Reid in Heron II) that the
tort test is more generous than the contract test because in a contractual
relationship you have the opportunity to warn the other side of
potential risks ("I really need you to get here on time as I don't
have a spare mill shaft"), where liability is concurrent and the
opportunity to warn exists you should apply the contract test.
If
you take the view that the contract test is determined by those
risks we have consented to run, where the tortious duty is similarly
based upon the assumption of responsibility the test should be the
same.
But
in Doughty v Turner (twisted) can it really be right that
the contract test trumps tort?
A
Ltd employs B to work dipping asbestos into a melt. Injuries from
splashes are, at the time of contracting, reasonably foreseeable
but no other injury. After B has started work it becomes apparent
that the asbestos can explode. B is subsequently seriously injured
because of carelessness for which A Ltd is responsible. A claim
is available in tort or in contract for the breach of an implied
duty to provide a safe system of work.
The
traditional formulation of the contract test would indicate that
the loss is too remote as the injury was not within the contemplation
of the parties at the time of contracting (H v B). Under
the formulation of the tort test in WM (1) as it was foreseeable
at the time of breach.
I
would have thought the more generous tort test must apply. B didn't
have the opportunity to warn of the risk - they didn't know of it.
The duty in tort is independent of any assumption of responsibility
by B Ltd.
Perhaps
Lord Denning's view in Parsons v Uttley is near (if not
quite) the truth after all - we have one rule for economic loss
(at least where dependent upon an assumption of responsibility)
and another for other forms of loss? We would have to modify our
traditional formulation of the rules though.
RS
-----
Original Message -----
From: Adam Kramer
Sent: Friday, February 11, 2005 5:39 PM
Subject: ODG: Remoteness
On
the latest discussion:
Price:
I agree with David that the price is relevant to remoteness. For
me it is because the price is a relevant factor in determining what
responsibility the other party can be assumed to have taken. I think
that the 'foreseeability without tacit assumption' theory collapses
in the face of the old taxi example:
Bill
Gates gets into a taxi at 11.30am and asks the driver how much it
costs to get to the airport. £15, says the driver. Bill tells the
driver that he has a meeting at the airport at 12pm with some very
easily-offended people, and that if he is late then a £100 million
deal will definitely collapse and Bill will personally lose £20
million in profits. He asks if the driver can promise to get him
to the airport in time for the meeting. "No problem guvnor", says
the driver. But he fails.
Of
course, the driver is not liable even though he foresaw (through
specially communicated information) that £20 million would be lost
as a result of breach of the undertaking to arrive by 12pm. However
if the driver had replied to Bill's question with: "No problem guvnor,
but the journey will cost you £100,000", then we can be sure that
the driver has assumed responsibility. The price increase has "signalised"
(Lightman QC, Seven Seas Properties Ltd. v Al-Essa (No. 2)
[1993] 1 WLR 1083 , 1088 (Ch D)) the assumption of responsibility.
The increase in price is not necessary for such an assumption -
if the taxi driver was known to be a billionaire or a compulsive
gambler, or the airport was next door, then Bill might also reasonably
interpret the driver as taking responsibility - but it does the
job.
Concurrent
liability and Doughty v Turner: I agree with Jason and
Andrew that contract limits tort. Anyway, where the tort duty is
due to an assumption of responsibility, the scope of that assumption
will be governed by exactly the same factors (at the same time-
the time of contracting/assuming responsibility) as the scope of
the contract duty - indeed, contract judges can learn a few tricks
from tort judges as to working out the scope of assumed responsibility
(see particularly Banque Bruxelles v Eagle Star / South Australia
Asset Management v York Montague). I think John Cartwright
talks about this in his classic article [1996] CLJ 488. Also, it
is my view that the scope of responsibility for personal injury
will not be as nicely sculpted by price/insurance and other known
factors, since most people cannot be reasonably assumed to take
responsibility for their own personal injury arising from breach
however cheap the service. Parsons v Uttley Ingham might
be based on similar reasoning. I have a sneaking suspicion that
there is still a problem in Robert's Doughty example though,
but will have to give it some wet-towel-around-the-head thinking.
Strict
Liability: Robert, I don't see a problem with contract liability
being strict and yet the scope of responsibility being often dependant
upon foreseeability. Both are subject to the parties' agreement,
it is merely that it is generally normal to take a promise as being
subject to strict liability but a scope of responsibility for consequences
that is limited by factors dependant upon why the promisor is making
the promise (to make money) etc.
<<<<
Previous Message ~ Index ~ Next
Message >>>>>
|