![]() |
RDG
online Restitution Discussion Group Archives |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
||||||||||||
|
Well, we are stumbling towards a principled distinction,
I think. This is between transactions which are fully executed on the
same occasion as they are agreed (such as payment of a debt, or a purchase
in a supermarket), and transactions which remain executory for a significant
period (such as a hire-purchase contract, or an interest rate swap). It
is only in the latter case that Duncan's special category of "actionable
mispredictions" arises. (Plainly, this cuts across the "contract"/"no
contract" distinction.)
The difficulty is that Duncan keeps using language which
refers to a single person's mental state ("mistake" and "misprediction"),
whereas it is elementary contract law that rights depend on what was agreed,
rather than on what one party thought they were agreeing to. So, for example,
if Duncan were describing the Fibrosa case, he has to say that the parties
"mistakenly believed" that war would not break out, or "mispredicted"
peace - both of which seem factually doubtful. In fact, we don't care
what the parties actually thought about the likelihood of war. The point
is that their agreement is only intelligible if we presuppose peace-time
conditions, and so may be said to embody an assumption that there would
be no war.
If harmony can be attained between the cases involving
contracts and the cases which don't, it can only be by using the same
concepts for each. "Mistake" doesn't cut it, because we then slide between
mistakes made by individuals, and mistaken assumptions implicit in contractual
wording. Whereas talk about the "common assumption" their transaction
embodies works in both contexts - we can talk of payment of a debt as
embodying the assumption that the money was due, without making any unprovable
statements about what was going through the parties' minds.
At 17:41 18/10/02 +0100, Duncan Sheehan wrote:
Dear all,
I think my response to Steve is yes,
but also no. Perhaps a pithy exposition of how I see mispredictions
would help.
A misprediction which becomes apparent,
because the belief becomes falsifiable, when the transaction/contract
is still executory or partially executed will count. That is I think
why frustration operates, as a misprediction that bites when the contract
is partially executed. If the prediction became falsifiable only after
full execution there would be no relief, and most cases of misprediction
on restitution fall into this category. May be I am just repeating myself
from my earlier email, but this is the principled reason for treating
some mispredictions differently. If the contract is partially executed
the misprediction affects what you actually do. If it is fully executed
it does not. If Steve is implying there is no principled basis, as I
think he is, I must disagree.
The part with which I do agree is where
Steve says "The question is not, ultimately, what the parties expected
or predicted, but what sort of circumstances their agreement provides
for."
True, up to a point. If we take the
risk of being mistaken we can have no relief, and Great Peace Shipping
confirms this for us. I do not think we have to abandon mistake though.
We need a cause of action, and I do not think not having provided for
the eventuality provides one. Taking the risk, or providing for the
occurrence may bar relief, but we still need the mistake to justify
relief in the first place. That said it won't be very often, certainly
not if Solle v Butcher really has gone, and we take a rather bold Court
of Appeal's word for it.
Steve Hedley
============================================= ansaphone : +44 1223 334931 Christ's College Cambridge CB2 3BU <== Previous message Back to index Next message ==> |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
» » » » » |
|
![]() |
|||||||||
![]() |