![]() |
RDG
online Restitution Discussion Group Archives |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
||||||||||||
|
At 02:26 PM 3/26/03 +0000, Peter Jaffey wrote:
I agree that the Blake full profit
measure should be exceptional. As I have suggested before I think it
should be available only where the claimant will suffer significant
uncompensable harm if the defendant does not perform the contract.
I have always been suspicious of this rationale for profits-based
recovery for breach of contract. I do not deny such a recovery where the
profits that the promisor obtained from her breach can help assess the
promisee's lost profits (for example, where both parties operate in similar
markets and with comparable skills). But in these cases traditional common
law grants such an award under the heading of the expectation interest.
The difficult cases, which were the focus of our attention in recent years,
are ones in which the promisor's profits are not a good (or even reasonable)
proxy of the promisee's loss. In such cases -- such as where the promisor
sells in a different market or where by the time the promisee covers in
the market, the market price equals the contract price -- a profits-based
recovery is, I would argue, inappropriate. Because it cannot serve as
the second-best to lost profits, looking at the promisor's profits cannot
reasonable help us solve the problem of undercompensation. The proper
solution for undercompensation in these cases is liquidated damages that
allow a promisee to assess (ex ante) the circumstances in which she may
be undercompensated due to loss that can be verified ex post only at a
prohibitively high cost.
Furthermore, not only that difficulties of proof do
not provide the rationale for awarding profits-based recovery for uncompensated
losses, but in fact I believe that proof difficulties -- this time difficulties
in proving the promisor's profits -- generally render such a measure of
recovery an undesirable pecuniary remedy. To see why, notice that while
traditional contract remedies, aimed at compensating a promisee for her
loss, require information that tends to be available to the promisee-plaintiff,
the data required for establishing the promisor's profits are much more
difficult to produce. Not only that a promisee needs to get information
regarding the promisor's affairs; she needs to resolve difficult questions
of causation and attribution. Contractual entitlements -- such as the
entitlement to the promisor's profits -- that rely on information that
can be verified only at a prohibitively high cost are inefficient. More
importantly, such entitlements create the very kind of uncertainty that
commercial parties dislike. Therefore, in most cases employing a profit-based
measure of recovery would undermine the probable intent of most such commercial
parties. Such inefficient defaults are not only undesirable from the promisor's
point of view, of course. They are also (ex ante) undesirable from the
promisee's perspective, at least insofar as commercial parties are concerned,
because the cost that the promisor is expected to incur -- and, hence,
the additional price she will charge the promisee -- due to such an inefficient
sanction for non-performance is, by definition, greater than the expected
benefit the promisee is likely to derive from such a remedy.
Hanoch
Hanoch Dagan <== Previous message Back to index Next message ==> |
||||||||||||
![]() |
![]() |
» » » » » |
|
![]() |
|||||||||
![]() |